Abstract
Whether democracy causes economic growth has been a matter of theoretical and empirical debate. We argue that looking at the average effect of democracy on long-run growth ignores the heterogeneity of growth experiences among authoritarian regimes relative to democratic regimes. Furthermore, the emphasis on long-run growth is not compatible with the stylized facts of economic growth in developing countries, which is characterized by frequent shifts in growth regimes from stagnant or declining growth to accelerations in growth and back again to decelerating growth. We examine the political determinants of the magnitude of growth in accelerations and deceleration episodes for 125 countries for 1950–2010. We find that the effect of the political regime on growth is asymmetric across accelerations and decelerations and that democracies do not necessarily outperform autocracies in a growth acceleration episode, though they are likely to prevent large growth collapses. We also highlight the importance of the type of autocracy in understanding the effects of regime type on growth.
1 Introduction
Whether democracy causes economic growth has been a matter of theoretical and empirical debate. A large literature has examined the relationship between democracy and economic growth, without reaching any firm conclusions. From a theoretical perspective, strong economic growth is possible under both autocracies and democracies. Positive economic growth may occur in autocracies if the autocrat is a “stationary bandit (that) has an encompassing interest in the territory he controls and accordingly provides domestic order and other public goods” (Olson 1993, p. 569). A leader in a democracy may also have a similar interest in providing law and order, and other public goods (Benabou 1996; Lizzeri and Persico 2004; Saint-Paul and Verdier 1993). Democracy can also provide a natural check to the power of kleptocratic leaders, reduce social conflict, and prevent powerful political groups from monopolizing economic opportunities (Acemoglu and Robinson 2012).
Autocratic leaders are also likely to have an adverse effect on growth, if the autocrat has a sufficiently short time horizon, so it would be in “his interest to confiscate the property of his subjects, to abrogate any contracts he has signed in borrowing money from them, and generally to ignore the long-run economic consequences of his choices” (Olson 1993, p. 572). At the same time, democratization may hurt economic growth if this leads to distortionary redistribution (Alesina and Rodrik 1994; Persson and Tabellini 1994). In addition, interest group politics are more prevalent in democracies, and their presence can lead to stagnation (Olson 1982).
The large empirical literature that has studied the democracy–growth relationship has also found an ambiguous result (Doucouliagos and Ulubasoglu 2008). In one of the early empirical contributions to this literature, Barro (1996) found that the overall effect of democracy on growth is weakly negative using repeated cross-sections for 84 countries. A similar finding is obtained by Tavares and Wacziarg (2001), also with cross-sectional data. On the other hand, Rodrik and Wacziarg (2005) and Persson and Tabellini (2007) find a positive effect, using panel data. Alesina and and Tabellini (2009) find that the cumulative number of years that a country spends in democracy has a positive effect on economic growth. More recently, Acemoglu et al. (2014) find a sizeable and robust effect of democracy on economic growth using annual panel data and a generalized method of moment estimators for 175 countries for 1960–2010. Their estimates suggest that a country that switches from nondemocracy to democracy achieves an increase in GDP per capita of about 20% in the next 30 years, a magnitude of income gain which is not particularly large, suggesting that the effect of democracy in increasing per capita incomes is quite muted.
The empirical literature on the effects of political regimes on growth suffers from two important limitations. First, much of the literature focuses on the effect of the political regime on long-run growth. However, such a focus on long-term growth is not consistent with the stylized facts of growth, where long-term average growth rates hide distinct medium-term episodes of successful growth and growth failures (Jones and Olken 2008).1 As recent literature on the empirics of growth highlights, economic growth in developing countries is characterized by “boom and bust” growth, with frequent shifts in growth re-gimes from stagnant or declining growth to accelerations in growth and back again to decelerating growth (Aizenman and Spiegel 2010; Arbache and Page 2007; Easterly et al. 1993; Hausmann et al. 2005, 2006; Jones and Olken 2008; Pritchett 2000; Rodrik 1999). Once we view economic growth as an episodic phenomenon, it is not clear how political institutions may be related to the large income gains and losses that we observe in growth acceleration and deceleration episodes.
A second limitation of the literature on the relationship between political institutions and growth is that it does not take into account that growth outcomes in autocracies tend to be more heterogeneous than in democracies with examples of both large growth successes and growth failures in autocracies as compared to democracies (Easterly 2011; Jones and Olken 2005). As Jones and Olken (2005) note, “democracies may be able to prevent the disastrous economic policies of Robert Mugabe in Zimbabwe or Samora Michel in Mozambigue; however, they might also have constrained the successful economic policies of Lee-Kwan Yew in Singapore or Deng Xiaoping in China” (p. 862). This suggests that focusing on the average effect of democracy on growth, as the previous empirical literature has attempted to do, may be misleading, as some types of autocracies are more likely to lead to more growth success than other types of autocracies. For example, autocracies where the leadership has long-term time horizons are more likely to enact growth-oriented policies than democracies where the leader has strong constraints on his executive power which prevents him from implementing growth-oriented reforms (Charron and La Puente 2011; Clague et al. 1996). In contrast, autocrats with short-term time horizons are likely to adopt policies that are inimical to growth.
In this article, we attempt to address these two limitations in the empirical literature on the relationship between the political regime and economic growth. First, instead of focusing on long-term growth, we study the political determinants of growth episodes. In particular, we examine whether the type of political regime has a causal effect on the income gains and losses that we observe in growth acceleration and deceleration episodes. We hypothesize that the effects of political institutions are asymmetrical across growth acceleration and growth deceleration episodes—while democracies are unlikely to out-perform autocracies in growth acceleration episodes, they are likely to lead to lower income losses as compared to autocracies in growth deceleration episodes.
Second, drawing from the literature that argues that party-based autocracies may have attributes that are likely to be more conducive to growth than other types of autocracies (Cheibub et al. 2010; Gelhbach and Keefer 2011), we study whether the heterogeneous growth outcomes that are associated with autocracies are related to the type of autocracy that is ruling the country at the onset of a growth episode. We differentiate between party-based autocracies on one hand and personalized, monarchist, and military-based autocracies on the other. We hypothesize that party-based autocracies are likely to yield a larger magnitude of growth in a growth episode as compared to other types of autocracies.
Our unit of analysis is growth episodes, which are identified by discrete breaks in the country’s rate of economic growth. A large literature has attempted to identify breaks in growth rates using subjective rule-based (filter-based) or statistical methods. We follow Kar et al. (2013), who provide a unified approach to identifying multiple breaks in growth rates, combining filter-based and statistical methods. Following this approach, we obtain 314 growth episodes for 125 countries from 1950 to 2010 with comparable Penn World Tables GDP per capita data.
The dependent variable in our empirical analysis is the magnitude of growth in the episode (which we define as the “episode magnitude”), which is the product of the actual growth rate in the episode relative to counterfactuals and the duration of the episode. In this article, we propose a procedure for estimating episode magnitude that takes into account the actual growth dynamics that we observe in the time-series data on GDP per capita. Episode magnitude of growth in any particular episode will be higher, the higher the duration of the episode, or the higher the actual growth rate as compared to a counterfactual growth rate.
Next, we estimate the effects of the political regime on the episode magnitude. We find clear evidence that democratic regimes are more likely to yield higher magnitudes of growth. However, differentiating between growth acceleration and growth deceleration episodes, we find that there is no discernible difference between democracies and autocracies in causing larger growth accelerations. Instead, democracies have a significant effect in preventing large growth collapses as compared to autocracies. This finding is in accordance with the theoretical literature, which suggests that we should not expect any performance difference between autocracies ruled by leaders with long-term time horizons and democracies when it comes to growth accelerations. On the other hand, democracies prevent the worst excesses of a predatory leader (as such a leader is likely to be voted out of office) as compared to autocracies where there are no checks on the predatory power of a dictator in the case of growth decelerations.
We then disaggregate authoritarian regimes by type of regime, and show that party-based authoritarian regimes outperform personalist, military-based, and monarchic authoritarian regimes in their effects on growth in such episodes. On the other hand, there is no discernible effect of the type of autocracy on episode magnitude in a growth deceleration episode. Again, our results are in accord with the theoretical literature, which highlights the importance of the type of autocracy in understanding the effects of regime type on growth.
The rest of the article is in six sections. The next section sets out our procedure for estimating the episode magnitude of growth. Section 3 discusses the theoretical literature and hypothesises on the relationship between political institutions and episode magnitude of growth. Section 4 presents the empirical strategy and Section 5 the data and descriptives. Section 6 presents the results. Section 7 concludes.
2 Identifying Growth Episodes and Estimating Episode Magnitudes
An episode-based analysis of growth is different from the Barro-type growth regressions or other standard regressions of long-term growth in two different ways. The first difference is that in standard regressions, the period over which growth is measured is decided in an ad hoc manner (say a decade) while episode-based approaches have to precisely define how to identify the length of an episode. The second difference is that while average growth rates are a suitable measure of the impact of growth in the standard regressions, they are not so in episode-based approaches, as the duration of episodes (which vary widely) is as important as the growth rate in this approach. In this section, we describe previous work that suggests a procedure to identify growth episodes (Kar et al. 2013) and introduces the concept of “episode magnitude” that we have defined as a measure of the impact of a growth episode (Pritchett et al. 2013). This measure combines in an intuitive way the impact of a change in the growth rate due to the episode, and the duration of the episode. Thus, for example, an acceleration to a modest growth rate which is sustained over decades may have a larger episode magnitude than a high but short-lived burst of growth.
2.1 Identifying Growth Episodes
Moving away from explaining long-term growth averages to explaining transitions between growth regimes necessitates the knowledge of the timing of the breaks in economic growth. Following Pritchett (2000), a set of recent studies attempted to identify breaks in growth rates of GDP per capita for countries with comparable income data. Two distinct approaches have been developed by this literature. The first is a “filter-based” approach that identifies growth breaks on the basis of subjectively defined rules. Using this approach, Hausmann et al. (2005) study breaks that involve growth accelerations, Hausmann et al. (2006) study growth collapses and Aizenman and Spiegel (2010) study takeoffs—periods of sustained high growth following periods of stagnation. The second approach is based on statistical structural break tests that use estimation and testing procedures to identify growth breaks in terms of statistically significant changes in (average) growth rates. The studies that have adopted the “statistical” approach have used the Bai-Perron (BP) methodology (1998), which locates and tests for multiple growth breaks within a time-series framework (Jones and Olken 2008).
Both approaches have serious shortcomings that call for a better alternative. The limitation of the filter-based approach is well known—the use of filters predetermined by the researcher is ad hoc, and leads to a lack of consistency in the identification of breaks across articles that use the filter-based approach. On the other hand, a significant short-coming with the statistical approach is that it is limited by the low power of the Bai-Perron test, which leads to the rejection of true breaks which are suggested by the behavior of the underlying GDP per capita series (Berg et al. 2012).
Kar et al. (2013) propose an approach that provides a unified framework for identifying breaks in economic growth drawing from filter-based and statistical approaches. They use a procedure for identifying structural breaks in economic growth that uses the Bai-Perron (BP, 1998) procedure of maximizing the F-statistic to identify candidate years for structural breaks in growth with thresholds on the magnitude of the shift to determine which are actual breaks (see Kar et al. 2013). This procedure involves the best fit of the BP method to the data in the first stage, and the application of a filter to the breaks identified in the first stage in the second stage. The magnitude filter was that the absolute value of the change in the growth rate after a BP potential break had to be (a) 2 percentage points if it was the first break; (b) 3 percentage points if the potential break was of the opposite sign of the previous break (an acceleration that followed a deceleration had to have accelerated growth by more than 3 ppa to qualify as a break); and (c) 1 percentage point if the BP potential break was of the same sign as the previous break, so if BP identified an acceleration that directly followed an acceleration (or deceleration that followed a previous deceleration), the magnitude had to be larger than 1 ppa to qualify as a break. To estimate potential breaks, we assumed that a “growth regime” lasts a minimum of 8 years (as in Berg et al. 2012). The use of shorter periods (e.g., 3 or 5 years) risks conflation with “business cycle fluctuations” or truly “short- run” shocks (e.g., droughts). Longer periods (e.g., 10 or 12 years) reduce the number of potential breaks.2 Application of this procedure to the PWT7.1 data for 125 countries3 for 1950–2010 identifies 314 structural breaks in growth, with some countries having no breaks (e.g., USA, France, Australia) and others having four breaks (e.g., Argentina, Zambia). Appendix A in Kar et al. (2013) provides a list of all 314 breaks identified by country and year of break.
2.2 Estimating the Episode Magnitude of Growth Accelerations and Decelerations
The calculation of episode magnitudes for growth episodes is discussed in detail in Pritchett et al. (2013). In this section we summarize this approach. We define the episode magnitude as the magnitude of the gain (or loss) in per capita income by the end of the episode, as a result of the growth in the episode. Equivalently, it is the product of (i) the additional growth during the episode and (ii) the duration of the episode. The additional growth during the episode is the difference between the actual growth rate during the episode, and a predicted counterfactual growth rate of the economy, had it not transitioned to this particular episode. How do we predict this counterfactual growth rate? One simple (although naive) prediction is that the growth rate would be what it was in the last episode (no change). This prediction however, ignores a very robust “stylized fact” about medium-term growth rates, that is, the tendency of these growth rates to “regress to the mean.” Like other volatile variables like returns on financial investments, medium term growth rates have been shown to have very low persistence, and hence for example, high growth in the current period increases the possibility of lower growth in the future (Easterly et al. 1993; Pritchett and Summers 2014). In terms of growth episodes, this implies that a predicted counterfactual growth rate can do much better than a “no change” assumption, by adopting some version of regression to mean.
There is another important reason why regression to mean needs to be incorporated in a definition of episode magnitudes. It should be noted that if there is a tendency of growth rates to regress to the mean, then it is a statistical phenomenon which is exhibited by many other variables. It is not causal in the sense that the reversal of growth rates in any episode for any particular country due to this tendency is not attributable to changes in the determinants of growth during that episode. Since our interest in defining an episode magnitude is to subsequently relate it to the underlying determinants of growth, our definition of this variable needs to remove the part that is due to this statistical phenomenon, leaving only that part of the variation in the growth outcome that can be explained by underlying factors. This implies that the measure of the success (or failure) of a growth episode has to be “over and above” its tendency to regress to the mean.
Based on these considerations, we propose three predicted “counterfactual” growth rates: (a) the growth rate in the previous episode, reflecting the idea of “no regression to mean”; (b) the world average growth rate during the episode, reflecting the idea of “complete regression to mean”; and (c) a predicted growth rate based on the idea of “partial regression to mean.” The “partial regression to mean” growth rate uses a regression for each country/episode to allow “predicted” growth to depend on a country’s initial GDP per capita, the episode period specific world average growth, and a flexibly specified regression to the mean.
Suppose we have a structural break in growth in year t that ends a previous growth episode. Also suppose the growth in the previous episode was gbefore that lasted for Nb years and the growth in the current episode is gep and this episode lasts Nep years. We define the episode magnitude of the current growth episode (where F denotes the episode) as the difference in logs between its actual GDP per capita (GDPPC) in year t + Nep, and its counterfactual level. If natural log of GDPPC is y then the equation is:
By definition, the righthand side of equation 1 is nothing but the product of the actual growth rate during the episode (relative to the counterfactual) and the duration of the episode. This definition of episode magnitude thus fulfills our criteria for a measure of the impact of a growth episode. Let us now formalize each of the three counterfactuals discussed above.
“No Regression to Mean” (NRM): Counterfactual growth continues at prebreak levels. This assumes there is zero regression to the mean and the counterfactual for growth during the episode was the prebreak growth rate.4 In this case the magnitude of the total gain/loss from the episode is:
“Complete regression to mean”: Counterfactual growth during the episode is world average (WA) growth during the episode. Complete regression to the mean assumes the growth rate during the episode would have been the world average growth during the same period.5
“Partial regression to mean” (PRM): Counterfactual growth during the episode is predicted from past growth. This counterfactual growth (denoted by gprm) is the prediction from a country/episode-specific regression of growth for all countries j other than the country with the break on a constant plus initial GDP per capita plus previous growth. We use a spline to allow the coefficient on previous growth to be different whether the country’s growth rate before the episode was higher or lower than the world average.
This functional form for the counterfactual growth allows for four things: (1) the constant αep allows the world average growth rate to vary over time and be specific to the period of the episode to accommodate a global “business cycle”; (2) regression to the mean is period-specific; (3) regression to the mean depends on previous growth (as recoveries from negative/slow growth may have different dynamics than the slowing of accelerations), with the persistence coefficients, βepbelow and βepabove capturing regression to the mean, if previous growth was below and above the previous world average growth rate respectively (with cj =1 and dj = 1 if the previous growth rate of the country in question was lower and higher than the previous world average growth rate respectively, 0 otherwise); (4) growth to depend on the initial level of income, given by the coefficient γ (without conditioning variables this is not estimating “conditional convergence”).6 The error term of the regression is given by εj.
The episode magnitude of a growth episode, using the “partial regression to mean” as the counterfactual growth rate, is given by:
Figure 1 illustrates the estimates of the episode magnitude for the three counterfactuals for the case of an acceleration from low growth to high growth. In this (hypothetical) case the “no regression to mean” counterfactual implies a very large magnitude, and the “complete regression to mean” counterfactual implies a small magnitude (as the post-acceleration growth is not much higher than the world average). The “partial regression to mean” counterfactual will essentially be a regression-determined weighted average of the two and hence will tend to be the two extremes. When using the “complete regression to mean” or “partial regression to mean” counterfactual, a growth acceleration could have a negative magnitude (or a growth deceleration could have a positive magnitude).
Episode Magnitude of a growth episode based on three counter-factuals.
We have estimated the episode magnitude for all 314 episodes based on the three counterfactual growth rates and these are reported in Pritchett et al. (2013) (Appendix 1). For our empirical exercises however, we will be using the two episode magnitudes based on the idea of regression to mean. Figure 2 gives a kernel density estimate of these two measures, representing the underlying statistical distribution for these variables. The kernel density plots of the two measures are significantly similar to each other, having a central tendency that is close to 0, and most of the density symmetrically distributed between -1 and 1.
Table 1 summarizes the regressions for calculating the “partial regression to the mean” growth rate. The regression constant, not surprisingly, shows substantial variability over time, as the “predicted” growth rate was positive from 1958 (the first possible growth break as spells have to be at least 8 years) to 1975, negative from 1975 to 1995, and then strongly positive from 1995 to 2002 (by construction the last growth break) as there was exceptionally strong growth.
Summary of the 314 Country/Episode-Specific Regressions Used to Compute “Partial Regression to the Mean” Growth Rates
. | . | . | . | Persistence coefficient . | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | . | Regression constant . | Coefficient on level of GDP per capita at beginning of episode . | (previous growth below world median) . | (previous growth above world median) . |
Average | 0.77 | 0.001 | 0.171 | 0.338 | |
“Standardized” persistence (impact of past growth on predicted growth) of an episode beginning in 1980, following an episode of 10 years and lasting 10 years | 0.125 | 0.388 | |||
Std. Deviation | 3.81% | 0.0038 | 0.348 | 0.319 | |
Before | 1975 | 1.16% | |||
Between | 1975 and 1995 | -1.25% | |||
After | 1995 | 7.37% |
. | . | . | . | Persistence coefficient . | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | . | Regression constant . | Coefficient on level of GDP per capita at beginning of episode . | (previous growth below world median) . | (previous growth above world median) . |
Average | 0.77 | 0.001 | 0.171 | 0.338 | |
“Standardized” persistence (impact of past growth on predicted growth) of an episode beginning in 1980, following an episode of 10 years and lasting 10 years | 0.125 | 0.388 | |||
Std. Deviation | 3.81% | 0.0038 | 0.348 | 0.319 | |
Before | 1975 | 1.16% | |||
Between | 1975 and 1995 | -1.25% | |||
After | 1995 | 7.37% |
The spline shows strong, and modestly asymmetric, regression to the mean. Countries with below world median growth show almost no persistence—the average coefficient on previous growth is only 0.175—while those with above average growth tended to have more persistence but still show strong regression to the mean. Since each country/episode regression is for different periods of “before” and “after” we adjust to a “standard” of the persistence coefficient for an episode 10 years in duration, starting after an episode of 10 years duration in 1980. We see the asymmetry is, if anything, stronger with very near zero persistence of slow growth (0.12) and substantial (but far from full) persistence of 0.388 for rapid growth.
3 The Relationship Between Political Institutions and Episode Magnitude of Growth
What would be our theoretical priors in understanding the effects of political institutions on the magnitude of growth in growth episodes? Consider two types of autocrats. The first type of leader has a long-term vision and a commitment to enact institutional reforms and policies that are likely to be growth enhancing (such as Deng Xiaoping in China).7 The second type of leader has a short-term vision (perhaps because he is in an unstable political environment where he may lose power), and engages in high levels of predation (such as Mugabe in Zimbabwe) (Clague et al. 1996). In an autocratic regime, both types of leaders have limited checks on their power to engage in growth-enhancing or growth-limiting policies (Olsen 1993).8 In the first case, a large episode of growth acceleration is likely to result, while in the second case, there is a likelihood of a growth collapse. In contrast, a leader in a democracy has strong constraints on his power with a large number of veto players in the political system (North and Weingast 1989). This does not allow him to enact growth-oriented policies with the same degree of freedom as the growth-oriented autocrat. Moreover, for a leader in a democracy, the long-term benefits of growth-oriented policies and reforms need to be balanced against the possible repercussions that such policies may have for the leader politically, if these policies and reforms are seen as being unpopular among the electorate or if the reforms lead to diminution of the rents that vested interests obtain from the prevalence of previous policies and sets of institutions (Krueger 1974).9 At the same time, the higher constraints on his executive power as well as the potential threat of losing power in future elections prevents him from engaging in the kind of predation that one may observe with an autocrat with kleptocratic tendencies (or if the leader in a democracy does engage in predatory policies that lead to a fall in income, there is a high chance that the leader will lose power in a future election) (Burke and Leigh 2010; Geddes 1999; Justesen and Kurrild-Klitgaard 2013). Therefore, political institutions—in this case, democracy—may have an asymmetrical effect on episode magnitude in growth acceleration and deceleration episodes, and we can hypothesize as follows:
H1: Democracies are unlikely to outperform autocracies in growth acceleration episodes. However, they are likely to yield lower income losses as compared to autocracies in growth deceleration episodes.
How autocrats behave with respect to long-term commitment to growth versus short-term predation would depend on the type of incentives as well as the constraints that autocrats face. In party-based autocracies, leader succession is typically institutionalized within the party structure, leading to lower uncertainty about what investors may expect when one leader makes way for the next leader (Wright 2008a). This also allows party-based autocracies to have long time horizons as the death of a leader does not imply the end of credible commitment from the leadership to a set of policies or institutions (Clague et al. 1996). In contrast, in personalist, monarchic, and military-based autocracies, leader succession is typically informal and ad hoc, leading to significant uncertainty on the part of the leader as to when he will be removed (Geddes 1999). This leads to short time horizons on the part of the leader, providing a strong incentive for him to engage in predatory and distortionary economic policy, and a weak commitment to institutions such as protection of property rights (Wright 2008b).
A second feature of party-based autocracies that makes them qualitatively different from nonparty-based autocracies with respect to growth outcomes is that leaders in party-based autocracies use ruling party institutionalization as a commitment device to investors (Gehlbach and Keefer 2011). By solving collective action problems within the ruling elite through institutionalization, autocrats signal their intention not to expropriate from investors who are members of the ruling party (as happened in China in the post-Mao area). Thus, party-based autocracies are more likely to observe higher investment than nonparty-based autocracies, leading to higher growth. This leads us to our second core hypothesis.
H2: Party-based autocracies are more likely to be associated with larger magnitudes of growth than nonparty-based autocracies during growth episodes.
4 Empirical Strategy
Our interest centers around the causal effect of the political regime on the magnitude of growth in the growth episodes we have identified from Section 2. To test our two core hypotheses, we estimate regressions of the following generic form:
where gm is our episode magnitude measure as discussed in Section 2, P is the measure of the political regime, Xkt is a vector of controls, δt are year effects, and eit is the error term. The subscript i denotes country, and j the growth episode in question for country i. Equation (1) does not make any distinction between growth accelerations and growth decelerations, and makes the restrictive assumption that the effect of political institutions on the magnitude of growth in acceleration and deceleration episodes is identical. We relax this assumption by estimating the effect of the political regime on episode magnitude in growth accelerations and decelerations separately, as follows:
Here, gma and gmd are the episode magnitudes in growth accelerations and growth decelerations, respectively.
As a measure of the type of political regime, we use POLITY, from Polity IV. This measure goes from -10 to +10, with regimes coded as -10 to 0 characterized as autocracies and regimes coded from 0 to +10 characterized as democracies.10 In addition to POLITY, we use a measure of the degree of constraints on the executive (XCONST), that captures the extent of institutionalized constraints on the decision-making powers of the chief executive, either individuals or collectivities.11 This measure has been widely used in the empirical literature on institutions and growth as the preferred measure of the degree that there are institutional mechanisms of credible commitment on the part of the state (Acemoglu et al. 2001; Besley and Persson 2011).
We use the values of POLITY and XCONST in the beginning year of the growth episode to address potential reverse causality issues—that is, the possibility that higher growth leads to better-quality political institutions, or that output contractions lead to more open political institutions (Burke and Leigh 2010). However, though we rely on Ordinary Least Squares as our primary method of estimation, we also use instrumental variables estimators as a robustness test.
To assess the effect of type of autocracy on episode magnitude, we use the classification of autocracies in the data set compiled by Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (GWF, 2014). GWF identifies 280 autocratic regimes during the period 1946–2010 in independent countries with more than one million inhabitants in 2009. Each country-year is coded autocratic, democratic, ruled by a provisional government charged with overseeing a transition to democracy, not independent, occupied by foreign troops, or lacking a central government. Autocracies are then classified into dominant-party, military, personalist, or monarchic autocracies, depending on whether the leadership group in control of policy, leadership selection, and the security apparatus is in the hands of a ruling party (party-based autocracies), a royal family (monarchy), the military (rule by a military institution), or a narrower group centered around an individual dictator (personalist dictatorships). We use the classification of type of autocracy at the beginning of the episode provided by GWF (each type of autocracy is coded as a dummy variable—1 if the regime is of a particular type, 0 otherwise; we create a dummy variable for nonparty-based autocracies, where the dummy is 1 if the autocracy is personalist, monarchic, or military, 0 otherwise).12
Our control variables are those that are standard in the growth empirics literature—the log of initial per capita income at the beginning of the episode to capture conditional convergence and also to control for the possibility that richer countries, who are mostly democracies, tend to grow more slowly (Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1992), trade openness (that is, exports plus imports as a ratio of GDP) (Dollar and Kraay 2004; Frankel and Romer 1999; Sachs and Warner 1995), resource rents as a ratio of GDP (Isham et al. 2005), and commodity price shocks13 (Burke and Leigh 2010). We would expect that trade-openness will have a positive effect on growth magnitude. On the other hand, the effects of resource rents and commodity price shocks on the magnitude of growth is indeterminate—a resource boom or a surge in commodity prices may lead to a boom in economic growth, but could also lead to a growth collapse, due to overinvestment in the initial years of the growth episode. We also use year fixed effects to incorporate common period shocks to GDP across all countries (e.g., an oil price increase or a global recession).
5 Data and Descriptive Statistics
5. Data
The data on political regimes are obtained from the Polity IV project hosted by the Centre for Systemic Peace (http://www.systemicpeace.org/polityproject.htm) and data on the type of autocracy is obtained from http://sites.psu.edu/dictators/. The data on per capita income, trade openness, and resource rents are obtained from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators. The data on commodity prices is obtained from Burke and Leigh (2010). The data on the ICRG protection of property rights (also to be used in the empirical analysis) is obtained directly from Political Risk Services (PRS) (https://www.prsgroup.com/).
5.2 Descriptive Statistics
We begin with looking at the top ten growth accelerations and growth decelerations ranked by the value of the episode magnitude obtained by the Partial Regression to the Mean procedure (Table 2). The largest growth acceleration episode occurred in Taiwan from 1962 to 1993, with Taiwan’s GDP per capita 170% higher than it would have been had it grown at the predicted rate versus the actual rate. The largest growth deceleration episode occurred in Iran from 1976 to 1987 with Iran’s GDP per capita 176% lower than it would have been had it grown at the predicted rate versus the actual rate. We also observe that nine of the ten countries with the largest growth acceleration episodes were autocracies at the beginning of their episodes. Similarly, nine of the ten countries with the largest growth deceleration episodes were autocracies at the beginning of their episodes. Interestingly, all the autocracies associated with the largest growth acceleration episodes are party-based autocracies, while the autocracies associated with the largest growth deceleration episodes are a mix of party-based, monarchic, military-based, and personalist autocracies. The higher variance in growth outcomes among autocracies as compared to democracies is also observed in Figure 3, where we see autocratic regimes have had the largest booms but also the largest busts, while growth outcomes have been far more bounded in both sides of the distribution for democracies.14
Top Growth Accelerations and Decelerations
. | . | . | Top Ten Growth Accelerations . | . | . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Country . | Year Started . | Year Ended . | Episode Magnitude . | Duration (years) . | Polity . | Constraints on Executive . | Autocracy? . |
Taiwan | 1962 | 1993 | 1.699 | 32 | -8 | 2 | Yes (Party-based) |
Indonesia | 1967 | 1995 | 1.01 | 28 | -7 | 2 | Yes (Party-based) |
Egypt | 1976 | 1991 | 0.908 | 16 | -6 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
China | 1977 | 1990 | 0.776 | 14 | -7 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
Vietnam | 1989 | 2010 | 0.717 | 21 | -7 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
Singapore | 1968 | 1979 | 0.698 | 12 | -2 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
Laos | 1979 | 2001 | 0.678 | 23 | -7 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
Trinidad and Tobago | 2002 | 2010 | 0.622 | 8 | 10 | 7 | No |
China | 1991 | 2010 | 0.606 | 19 | -7 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
Albania | 1992 | 2010 | 0.595 | 18 | 5 | 5 | No |
Top Ten Growth Decelerations | |||||||
Country | Year Started | Year Ended | Episode Magnitude | Duration | Polity | Constraints on Executive | Authoritarian? |
Iran | 1976 | 1987 | -1.755 | 12 | -10 | 1 | Yes (Monarchy) |
Afghanistan | 1986 | 1993 | -1.201 | 8 | -8 | 2 | Yes (Party-based) |
Malawi | 1978 | 2001 | -1.195 | 24 | -9 | 1 | Yes (Personalist) |
Congo, Dem. Republic | 1989 | 1999 | -1.086 | 11 | -10 | Yes (Personalist) | |
Iraq | 1979 | 1990 | -1.061 | 12 | -9 | 1 | Yes (Party-based) |
Jordan | 1965 | 1973 | -0.996 | 9 | -9 | 2 | Yes (Monarchy) |
Trinidad and | 1980 | 1988 | -0.958 | 9 | 8 | 7 | No |
Tobago | |||||||
Jordan | 1982 | 1990 | -0.928 | 9 | 210 | 1 | Yes (Monarchy) |
Brazil | 1980 | 2001 | -0.898 | 22 | 24 | 1 | Yes (Military) |
Somalia | 1978 | 2010 | -0.862 | 32 | 27 | 1 | Yes (Personalist) |
. | . | . | Top Ten Growth Accelerations . | . | . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Country . | Year Started . | Year Ended . | Episode Magnitude . | Duration (years) . | Polity . | Constraints on Executive . | Autocracy? . |
Taiwan | 1962 | 1993 | 1.699 | 32 | -8 | 2 | Yes (Party-based) |
Indonesia | 1967 | 1995 | 1.01 | 28 | -7 | 2 | Yes (Party-based) |
Egypt | 1976 | 1991 | 0.908 | 16 | -6 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
China | 1977 | 1990 | 0.776 | 14 | -7 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
Vietnam | 1989 | 2010 | 0.717 | 21 | -7 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
Singapore | 1968 | 1979 | 0.698 | 12 | -2 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
Laos | 1979 | 2001 | 0.678 | 23 | -7 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
Trinidad and Tobago | 2002 | 2010 | 0.622 | 8 | 10 | 7 | No |
China | 1991 | 2010 | 0.606 | 19 | -7 | 3 | Yes (Party-based) |
Albania | 1992 | 2010 | 0.595 | 18 | 5 | 5 | No |
Top Ten Growth Decelerations | |||||||
Country | Year Started | Year Ended | Episode Magnitude | Duration | Polity | Constraints on Executive | Authoritarian? |
Iran | 1976 | 1987 | -1.755 | 12 | -10 | 1 | Yes (Monarchy) |
Afghanistan | 1986 | 1993 | -1.201 | 8 | -8 | 2 | Yes (Party-based) |
Malawi | 1978 | 2001 | -1.195 | 24 | -9 | 1 | Yes (Personalist) |
Congo, Dem. Republic | 1989 | 1999 | -1.086 | 11 | -10 | Yes (Personalist) | |
Iraq | 1979 | 1990 | -1.061 | 12 | -9 | 1 | Yes (Party-based) |
Jordan | 1965 | 1973 | -0.996 | 9 | -9 | 2 | Yes (Monarchy) |
Trinidad and | 1980 | 1988 | -0.958 | 9 | 8 | 7 | No |
Tobago | |||||||
Jordan | 1982 | 1990 | -0.928 | 9 | 210 | 1 | Yes (Monarchy) |
Brazil | 1980 | 2001 | -0.898 | 22 | 24 | 1 | Yes (Military) |
Somalia | 1978 | 2010 | -0.862 | 32 | 27 | 1 | Yes (Personalist) |
In our sample of 288 growth episodes for which we have data on POLITY,15 we see that both the distributions of POLITY and XCONST are sharply twin peaked, with countries in our sample either being strongly autocratic (with limited constraints on their executives) or strongly democratic (with strong constraints on their executives) at the beginning of their growth episodes (Figures 4 and 5).
In Figures 6 and 7, we plot the bivariate relationships between episode magnitude and POLITY, and between episode magnitude and XCONST, respectively. We observe a weak positive relationship between the magnitude of growth and democracy/constraints on the executive.
Next, we examine whether the average magnitude of growth in an episode differs by political regime (Table 3). While the average magnitude of growth across all episodes is negative for both autocracies and democracies, democratic regimes perform better than autocratic regimes on average across all episodes, with a lower average income loss (-0.005 versus -0.068) and a lower standard deviation (0.326 versus 0.438). However, disaggregating the data by growth accelerations and decelerations, we find that autocratic regimes have a higher magnitude of growth in growth accelerations than democratic regimes, suggesting that in a boom, autocracies see higher income gains than democracies. At the same time, the standard deviation of the episode magnitude is higher in autocracies than in democracies, indicating the higher volatility in growth outcomes for autocracies.
Episode Magnitude, Summary Statistics, by Regime Type
Political Regime . | Number of Observations . | Mean . | Standard Deviation . | Minimum . | Maximum . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Autocratic Regimes | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 154 | -0.068 | 0.438 | -1.755 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 65 | 0.321 | 0.266 | 0.006 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 89 | -0.358 | 0.292 | -1.755 | -0.001 |
Democratic Regimes | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 133 | -0.005 | 0.326 | -1.086 | 0.771 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 66 | 0.255 | 0.192 | 0.006 | .771 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 67 | -0.256 | 0.211 | -1.086 | -0.002 |
Political Regime . | Number of Observations . | Mean . | Standard Deviation . | Minimum . | Maximum . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Autocratic Regimes | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 154 | -0.068 | 0.438 | -1.755 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 65 | 0.321 | 0.266 | 0.006 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 89 | -0.358 | 0.292 | -1.755 | -0.001 |
Democratic Regimes | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 133 | -0.005 | 0.326 | -1.086 | 0.771 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 66 | 0.255 | 0.192 | 0.006 | .771 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 67 | -0.256 | 0.211 | -1.086 | -0.002 |
In contrast, in growth decelerations, autocracies witness larger income losses than democracies (an average episode magnitude of growth of -0.358 for autocracies as compared to -0.256 for democracies), again with a higher standard deviation (0.292 for autocracies versus 0.211 for democracies). This suggests that a focus on the average effect of democracy on growth outcomes is misleading, as autocracies are likely to observe larger booms as well as larger busts than democracies.
Do growth outcomes differ by the type of autocracy? Table 4 suggests that it does, with party-based autocracies likely to witness a higher magnitude of growth on average across all episodes as compared to military regimes, monarchies, and personalized autocracies (an average of 0.004 for party-based autocracies, as compared to -0.117 for military regimes, -0.245 for monarchies, and -0.111 for personalized regimes). In the case of growth accelerations, party-based autocracies significantly outperform all other types of autocracy, with an average episode magnitude of 0.393, as compared to 0.282 for military regimes, -0.245 for monarchies, and 0.233 for personalized regimes. When it comes to growth decelerations, the picture is mixed, with personalist monarchies having the lowest income loss among all types of autocracy (an average of -0.317 for personalized regimes as compared to -0.336 for party-based autocracies, -0.383 for military regimes, and -0.735 for monarchies).
Episode Magnitude, Summary Statistics, by Type of Autocracy
Political Regime . | Number of Observations . | Mean . | Standard Deviation . | Minimum . | Maximum . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Party-Based Regimes | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 88 | 0.004 | 0.464 | -1.201 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 41 | 0.393 | 0.326 | 0.033 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 47 | -0.336 | 0.248 | -1.201 | -0.008 |
Military Regimes | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 35 | -0.117 | 0.417 | -0.898 | 0.771 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 14 | 0.282 | 0.257 | 0.030 | 0.771 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 21 | -0.383 | 0.258 | -0.898 | -0.012 |
Monarchies | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 14 | -0.245 | 0.639 | -1.755 | 0.436 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 7 | 0.245 | 0.158 | 0.066 | 0.436 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 7 | -0.735 | 0.548 | -1.755 | -0.091 |
Personalist Autocracies | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 40 | -0.111 | 0.355 | -1.195 | 0.410 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 15 | 0.233 | 0.126 | 0.008 | 0.410 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 25 | -0.317 | 0.279 | -1.195 | -0.005 |
Political Regime . | Number of Observations . | Mean . | Standard Deviation . | Minimum . | Maximum . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Party-Based Regimes | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 88 | 0.004 | 0.464 | -1.201 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 41 | 0.393 | 0.326 | 0.033 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 47 | -0.336 | 0.248 | -1.201 | -0.008 |
Military Regimes | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 35 | -0.117 | 0.417 | -0.898 | 0.771 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 14 | 0.282 | 0.257 | 0.030 | 0.771 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 21 | -0.383 | 0.258 | -0.898 | -0.012 |
Monarchies | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 14 | -0.245 | 0.639 | -1.755 | 0.436 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 7 | 0.245 | 0.158 | 0.066 | 0.436 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 7 | -0.735 | 0.548 | -1.755 | -0.091 |
Personalist Autocracies | |||||
Episode Magnitude, All Episodes | 40 | -0.111 | 0.355 | -1.195 | 0.410 |
Episode Magnitude, Accelerations | 15 | 0.233 | 0.126 | 0.008 | 0.410 |
Episode Magnitude, Decelerations | 25 | -0.317 | 0.279 | -1.195 | -0.005 |
Summary Statistics, All Variables
Variable . | Number of Observations . | Mean . | Standard Deviation . | Minimum . | Maximum . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Episode Magnitude, All | 314 | -0.044 | 0.394 | -1.755 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Only Accelerations | 144 | 0.282 | 0.236 | 0.006 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Only Decelerations | 170 | -0.320 | 0.270 | -1.755 | -0.001 |
POLITY | 287 | -0.341 | 7.388 | -10 | 10 |
XCONST | 287 | 3.756 | 2.347 | 1 | 7 |
Initial Per Capita Income (ln) | 314 | 7.931 | 1.205 | 5.115 | 10.515 |
Trade/GDP (%) | 299 | 67.58 | 47.20 | 2.137 | 373.179 |
Resource Rents/GDP (%) | 293 | 7.640 | 10.814 | 0 | 61.723 |
Commodity Price Shocks | 282 | -0.022 | 0.090 | -0.277 | 0.269 |
Variable . | Number of Observations . | Mean . | Standard Deviation . | Minimum . | Maximum . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Episode Magnitude, All | 314 | -0.044 | 0.394 | -1.755 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Only Accelerations | 144 | 0.282 | 0.236 | 0.006 | 1.699 |
Episode Magnitude, Only Decelerations | 170 | -0.320 | 0.270 | -1.755 | -0.001 |
POLITY | 287 | -0.341 | 7.388 | -10 | 10 |
XCONST | 287 | 3.756 | 2.347 | 1 | 7 |
Initial Per Capita Income (ln) | 314 | 7.931 | 1.205 | 5.115 | 10.515 |
Trade/GDP (%) | 299 | 67.58 | 47.20 | 2.137 | 373.179 |
Resource Rents/GDP (%) | 293 | 7.640 | 10.814 | 0 | 61.723 |
Commodity Price Shocks | 282 | -0.022 | 0.090 | -0.277 | 0.269 |
6 Results
We now turn to the estimation of equations (1), (2a), and (2b). Table 5 presents the summary statistics of the variables included in the regressions and Table 6 presents the main results. In columns (1) and (2), we present the results of the basic specification of equation (1) estimated with Ordinary Least Squares, without controls (initial level of per capita income, trade/GDP, resource rents/GDP, and commodity price shocks) but with the year fixed effects included in the regressors. We first estimate equation (1) with the POLITY measure and then with XCONST as our key Right-Hand Side (RHS) variable. We find that democracy as well as higher degree of constraints on the executive has a positive effect on the magnitude of growth. When we add the control variables in columns (3) and (4), the main results do not change—the coefficients on POLITY and XCONST are positive and significant. This suggests that on average, more democratic regimes are likely to observe a higher magnitude of growth.
Regression Results: Does the Political Regime Matter?
. | All Episodes . | Growth Accelerations . | Growth Decelerations . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Explanatory Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . |
POLITY | 0.007* | 0.014*** | — | — | 0.002 | — | 0.011** | — |
(0.051) | (0.001) | (0.678) | (0.010) | |||||
XCONST | — | — | 0.022** | 0.042*** | — | 0.003 | — | 0.041** |
(0.034) | (0.002) | (0.820) | (0.005) | |||||
Initial Per Capita Income (ln) | — | -0.091*** | — | -0.036 | -0.037 | -0.035 | -0.016 | -0.023 |
(0.001) | (0.159) | (0.147) | (0.174) | (0.575) | (0.434) | |||
Trade/GDP 2 | — | 0.002*** | — | 0.002*** | 0.001** | 0.001** | 0.001** | 0.001** |
(0.001) | (0.000) | (0.019) | (0.020) | (0.014) | (0.015) | |||
Resource Rents/GDP | — | 0.001 | — | -0.001 | 0.004 | 0.004 | -0.004** | -0.004* |
(0.735) | (0.350) | (0.164) | (0.178) | (0.031) | (0.056) | |||
Commodity Price Shocks | — | 0.053 | 0.258 | 0.377 | 0.369 | -0.582* | -0.615* | |
(0.868) | (0.83) | (0.180) | (0.189) | (0.060) | (0.053) | |||
Year Effects | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
R-square | 0.20 | 0.21 | 0.16 | 0.21 | 0.35 | 0.34 | 0.42 | 0.43 |
Number of Observations | 287 | 254 | 258 | 254 | 114 | 114 | 140 | 140 |
. | All Episodes . | Growth Accelerations . | Growth Decelerations . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Explanatory Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . |
POLITY | 0.007* | 0.014*** | — | — | 0.002 | — | 0.011** | — |
(0.051) | (0.001) | (0.678) | (0.010) | |||||
XCONST | — | — | 0.022** | 0.042*** | — | 0.003 | — | 0.041** |
(0.034) | (0.002) | (0.820) | (0.005) | |||||
Initial Per Capita Income (ln) | — | -0.091*** | — | -0.036 | -0.037 | -0.035 | -0.016 | -0.023 |
(0.001) | (0.159) | (0.147) | (0.174) | (0.575) | (0.434) | |||
Trade/GDP 2 | — | 0.002*** | — | 0.002*** | 0.001** | 0.001** | 0.001** | 0.001** |
(0.001) | (0.000) | (0.019) | (0.020) | (0.014) | (0.015) | |||
Resource Rents/GDP | — | 0.001 | — | -0.001 | 0.004 | 0.004 | -0.004** | -0.004* |
(0.735) | (0.350) | (0.164) | (0.178) | (0.031) | (0.056) | |||
Commodity Price Shocks | — | 0.053 | 0.258 | 0.377 | 0.369 | -0.582* | -0.615* | |
(0.868) | (0.83) | (0.180) | (0.189) | (0.060) | (0.053) | |||
Year Effects | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
R-square | 0.20 | 0.21 | 0.16 | 0.21 | 0.35 | 0.34 | 0.42 | 0.43 |
Number of Observations | 287 | 254 | 258 | 254 | 114 | 114 | 140 | 140 |
The first of our core hypotheses is that democracy and constraints on the executive are likely to have a different effect on growth accelerations as compared to growth decelerations. To test this hypothesis, we estimate equations (2a) and (2b), with controls and year effects, with POLITY and XCONST included in turn as the key explanatory variable. We present these results in columns (5) and (6) for growth accelerations, and in columns (7) and (8) for growth decelerations. We find that POLITY and XCONST do not have any discernible effect on the magnitude of growth during a growth acceleration—the coefficients on these two variables are statistically not different from zero, both with and without controls. However, both POLITY and XCONST are positive and statistically significant for growth decelerations. This supports our hypothesis that democracy and the constraints on the executive and political competition matter more in limiting negative growth episodes than in enhancing positive growth episodes. Thus, the greater the extent of democracy and the constraints on the executive, the less likely the possibility of growth collapses, without any discernible change in the likelihood of growth booms.
With respect to the control variables, trade openness as expected has a positive effect on growth magnitude, while resource rents and commodity price shocks do not have any discernible negative effect on growth magnitude. The initial level of per capita income does not have a discernible effect on growth magnitude, suggesting that the magnitude of growth is not systematically related to the level of per capita income at the beginning of the episode.
6.1 Robustness Tests
One possibility with our main regression results as in Table 6 is that both the magnitude of growth and our key political institutions are correlated with unobserved country characteristics. This is a remote possibility as the maximum number of episodes for any country is three, and the average number of episodes per country is two. Nevertheless, to test for this possibility, we include country fixed effects in our set of controls (columns (4) to (6)). Here, and in the rest of the robustness tests in Table 7, we focus on the constraints on the executive as our preferred variable to capture political institutions.16 We find that the coefficient on constraints to the executive remain statistically significant at the 1% level (column (1)).17
Robustness Tests
Explanatory Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Growth Accelerations | ||||
XCONST | 0.017 | -0.002 | 0.010 | 0.029 |
(0.523) | (0.896) | (0.640) | (0.467) | |
Protection of Property Rights | – | – | 0.036 | – |
(0.128) | ||||
Controls | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Year Effects | NO | YES | YES | YES |
R-square | 0.19 | 0.32 | 0.44 | – |
Hansen’s J Test | – | – | – | 0.427 |
(0.513) | ||||
F statistic | – | – | – | 3.44*** |
Number of Observations | 114 | 103 | 75 | 76 |
Growth Decelerations | ||||
XCONST | 0.050* | 0.041*** | 0.038** | 0.090** |
(0.066) | (0.005) | (0.023) | (0.023) | |
Protection of Property Rights | – | – | 0.013 | – |
(0.607) | ||||
Controls | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Year Effects | NO | YES | YES | YES |
R-square | 0.20 | 0.44 | 0.48 | – |
F statistic | – | – | – | 1.97** |
Hansen’s J Test | – | – | – | 2.60 |
(0.110) | ||||
Number of Observations | 140 | 130 | 112 | 90 |
Explanatory Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Growth Accelerations | ||||
XCONST | 0.017 | -0.002 | 0.010 | 0.029 |
(0.523) | (0.896) | (0.640) | (0.467) | |
Protection of Property Rights | – | – | 0.036 | – |
(0.128) | ||||
Controls | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Year Effects | NO | YES | YES | YES |
R-square | 0.19 | 0.32 | 0.44 | – |
Hansen’s J Test | – | – | – | 0.427 |
(0.513) | ||||
F statistic | – | – | – | 3.44*** |
Number of Observations | 114 | 103 | 75 | 76 |
Growth Decelerations | ||||
XCONST | 0.050* | 0.041*** | 0.038** | 0.090** |
(0.066) | (0.005) | (0.023) | (0.023) | |
Protection of Property Rights | – | – | 0.013 | – |
(0.607) | ||||
Controls | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Year Effects | NO | YES | YES | YES |
R-square | 0.20 | 0.44 | 0.48 | – |
F statistic | – | – | – | 1.97** |
Hansen’s J Test | – | – | – | 2.60 |
(0.110) | ||||
Number of Observations | 140 | 130 | 112 | 90 |
A second robustness test we perform is to determine whether our results are sensitive to the exclusion of the truncated episodes (i.e., episodes that begin in 2002 and end in 2010 due to lack of data availability after that year). Dropping all post-2002 episodes, we find no change in our finding that constraints on the executive has a positive and statistically significant effect on episode magnitude for growth deceleration episodes but there is no such positive effect for growth acceleration episodes (column (2)).
One other possibility of omitted variable bias is that our measures of political institutions may be correlated with the quality of economic institutions, and it is the latter which may explain the association we have found so far between our preferred measures of political institutions and the magnitude of growth. To address this possibility, we include the ICRG measure of the protection of rights that is commonly used in the econometric analysis of the effects of institutions on economic growth (Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2001; Rodrik, Subramanian, and Trebbi 2004). This measure is only available from 1984, and so we confine our analysis to growth episodes that begin in 1984 or later. We find that our main finding—that higher constraints on the executive limit the likelihood of large growth collapses but do not necessarily increase the likelihood of large growth booms—is remarkably robust to the inclusion of economic institutions on the RHS and to the reduction in the sample (column (3)).
Next, we explore the possibility that there may be reverse causality in the positive relationship between our core political institution variable and the episode magnitude, with the positive growth episodes (or less negative growth episodes) leading to greater state capacity (as captured by the strengthening of the constraints that are placed on executives) and democratization (Burke and Leigh 2010). To address the possibility of reverse causality, we use Two Squares Least Squares (2SLS) estimates and two standard instruments proposed in the institutions literature—the settler mortality rate proposed by Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (AJR, 2001) and the ethnic fractionalization measure proposed by Alesina et al. (2003).18 The 2SLS estimates of the effect of XCONST on episode magnitude is almost twice the size of the OLS estimate for growth decelerations, and is significant at the 5% level, suggesting that endogeneity may have been a concern with the OLS estimates (column (4)).19 For growth accelerations, as with the OLS estimates, the coefficient on constraints on the executive is statistically not different from zero in the 2SLS estimate. Our finding that the coefficient on the core political institutions variable remains positive and significant in the 2SLS estimates increases our confidence that higher constraints on the executive are a cause and not a consequence of a lower likelihood of a fall in incomes during a growth collapse.
Finally, we look at the effect of type of autocracy on episode magnitude in Table 8. We find that, along with democratic regimes, party-based autocracies lead to larger magnitude of growth across all growth episodes (column (1)).20 When we disaggregate episodes by whether the episode is an acceleration or a deceleration, we find that party-based autocracies and democracies are both likely to yield larger acceleration episodes (column (2)).21 Interestingly, the effect of party-based autocracies on episode magnitude is larger than that of democracies. In contrast, in growth deceleration episodes, party-based autocracies do not perform better than other types of autocracies in preventing large growth collapses. The effect of democracy in reducing the magnitude of income loss in a deceleration episode, as found earlier, remains, even when we control for the type of autocracy. These results provide some support for our second core hypothesis: that party-based autocracies are likely to yield larger magnitudes of growth in growth episodes—however, we find that while party-based autocracies outperform nonparty-based autocracies in growth acceleration episodes, there is no such difference in growth deceleration episodes. Here, democracies do better than all types of autocracies in preventing large income losses in growth deceleration episodes.
Further Regression Results: Does the Type of Autocracy Matter?
Explanatory Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Party-Based Autocracy | 0.139* | 0.164** | 0.084 |
(0.062) | (0.019) | (0.259) | |
Democracy | 0.241*** | 0.144* | 0.126* |
(0.001) | (0.060) | (0.088) | |
Controls | YES | YES | YES |
Year Effects | YES | YES | YES |
R-square | 0.35 | 0.43 | 0.42 |
Number of Observations | 240 | 113 | 127 |
Explanatory Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Party-Based Autocracy | 0.139* | 0.164** | 0.084 |
(0.062) | (0.019) | (0.259) | |
Democracy | 0.241*** | 0.144* | 0.126* |
(0.001) | (0.060) | (0.088) | |
Controls | YES | YES | YES |
Year Effects | YES | YES | YES |
R-square | 0.35 | 0.43 | 0.42 |
Number of Observations | 240 | 113 | 127 |
Conclusions
In this article, we take a fresh look at the democracy–growth relationship, focusing on medium-term growth episodes rather than long-term growth. Drawing from the theoretical literature, we hypothesize that democracies are not likely to outperform autocracies in growth accelerations, though they would prevent large growth collapses. We also hypothesize that party-based autocracies would be more likely to be associated with large growth accelerations than monarchic, military-based, and personalistic monarchies. Using 314 growth episodes for 125 countries for 1950–2010 and a new measure of quantifying the magnitude of growth in episodes of growth, we find strong evidence in support of our two hypotheses. Our focus on episodic growth rather than long-term growth allows us to show that the effect of the political regime on growth is asymmetric across accelerations and decelerations. We also highlight the importance of the type of autocracy in understanding the effects of regime type on growth.
Notes
Furthermore, as Acemoglu et al. (2008) note, the positive association between democracy and long-run economic development may be driven by historical factors that shaped the divergent political and economic paths of different societies.
The length of the output data series that is available in the Penn World Tables vary from country to country. This implies that we need to specify a maximum number of candidate breaks for each country depending on the length of the data series available. We postulate that a country with: (i) 40 years of data (only since 1970), can have a maximum of two breaks; (ii) more than 40 years and up to 55 years (data since 1955), can have a maximum of three breaks; (iii) more than 55 years (before 1955), can have a maximum of four breaks.
From the PWT7.1 data we eliminated all countries that had very small populations (less than 700,000 in 1980) and those that did not have data since 1970 (which eliminated many former Soviet sphere countries and some oil countries like Kuwait and Saudi Arabia).
The NRM growth rate is the coefficient from an OLS regression of ln(GDPPC) on a time trend over the prebreak period.
The world average growth rate is the average of the growth rates of all countries minus the country in question for the period of the growth episode.
For the period from the beginning of the data to the first growth break, the PRM growth rate is just a regression of growth on the natural log level of initial output.
As Londregan and Poole (1990) note, even authoritarian governments have powerful incentives to promote growth, not out of concern for the welfare of their citizens but because poor economic performance may lead to their removal by force.
As De Luca et al. (2015) show, autocrats may obtain support from elites if they can generate higher growth rates than under democracies, effectively reducing any threat to their staying in power.
For example, trade reforms that may increase economic growth in the medium term may be unpopular if they lead to job losses or the reduction of profits of protected politically influential firms.
Each country-year observation in Polity IV is coded according to (a) the competitiveness and open-ness of executive recruitment; (b) the competitiveness and regulation of political participation and the (c) the constraints on the executive. Mature democracies according to this measure are regimes where there is the presence of institutions and procedures through which citizens can express effective preferences about alternative policies and leaders, the existence of institutionalized constraints on the exercise of power by the executive, and the guarantee of civil liberties to all citizens in their daily lives and in acts of political participation. Mature autocracies on the other hand sharply restrict or suppress competitive political participation. Their chief executives are chosen in a regularized process of selection within the political elite, and once in office they exercise power with few institutional constraints (Marshall et al. 2011).
The variable XCONST varies from a value of 1, when there are no regular limitations on the executive’s actions, to a value of 7, when accountability groups have effective authority equal to or greater than the executive in most areas of activity.
We found strong overlap between POLITY and GWF on regimes that were characterized as autocratic in the respective data sets.
We measure the latter as the difference in the average of real commodity prices 3 years after the onset of the episode and the average of real commodity prices for the 3 years before the onset of the episode.
We classify democracies as those countries with a POLITY measure between 0 and 10, and autocracies as those countries with a POLITY measure between -10 and 0.
We omit the episodes where Polity IV coded these episodes as interruption, interregnum, and transitional periods as the type of political regime for these episodes was indeterminate.
In all our robustness tests, we also used POLITY as the key RHS variable, with no change in our results.
We also examined whether our results are sensitive to our calculation of the magnitude of growth using the “unconditional predicted” counterfactual growth rate. As a robustness test, we used our estimates of episode magnitude using the “world average” counterfactual growth rate, and find that there is no change in our results.
The settler mortality rate is an indirect measure of the disease environment in the colonies, and thus, measures the likelihood of Europeans settling in a particular colony and setting up institutions of private property. AJR find that there is a high correlation between the mortality rates faced by soldiers, bishops, and sailors in the colonies and European settlements and early measures of institutions, and between early institutions and current institutions. As AJR show, the settler mortality rate is not able to explain current development outcomes directly and thus meets the exclusion restriction for a valid instrument. With respect to the ethnic fractionalization measure, Alesina and Zhuravskaya (2011) show that this measure is negatively related to a variety of institutional measures including the quality of government and the rule of law.
The underidentification and the instrument suitability test (Hansen J statistic) show that the estimation does not suffer from a weak instruments problem.
In the regressions, we include two dummy variables, one if the regime is a party-based autocracy, and the other if the regime is a democracy. The residual category is nonparty-based autocracies.
We exclude the country-episode observations where the country is ruled by a provisional government charged with overseeing a transition to democracy, not independent, occupied by foreign troops, or lacking a central government.